Laissez Faire, by Garet Garrett

The shivering ghost that now inhabits the words laissez faire was once an unconquerable fighting spirit. It did not belong to capitalism. It belonged to liberty; and to this day its association with capitalism is valid only inso­far as capitalism represents liberty.

When the great struggle for individual liberty began in Europe, the one interest that controlled the life of the mind was religion. What men wanted most of all was freedom to worship God in their own way, freedom to be­lieve or disbelieve; and for that they went to death at the stake intoning their hymns of heresy. The religious wars were terrible. They lasted until the lust of fanaticism was sated. Then reason rebelled and there was peace, founded on the principle of laissez faire in religion. That is not what anyone called it at that time, because the words had not yet been invented; but that is what it was. Thereafter, so far as religion was concerned, the individ­ ual was to be let alone.

Great transactions of the human spirit have momen­tum, displacement, and direction, but no sharp edges; there is no sudden passage from one time to another. Long af ter the principle of laissez faire had been accepted in Europe, religious tyranny continued. Men were free to join any church they liked, but if they chose, for exam­ple, to be Calvinists, they found themselves enthralled by a discipline that claimed jurisdiction not only over their souls but over their everyday life and all their eco­nomic behavior.

The next phase of the great European struggle for lib­erty, therefore, was aimed at freedom of enterprise. To say that religious radicalism was followed by economic radicalism is merely to make a statement of chronological fact. How were the two things related? Were they but two aspects of one thing? In the preface to Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, R. H. Tawney says:

. . . . the existence of a connection between economic radical­ ism arid religious radicalism was to those who saw both at first­ hand something not far from a platitude. Until some reason is produced for rejecting their testimony, it had better be assumed that they knew what they were talking about. How precisely that connection should be conceived is, of course, a different question. It had, obviously, two sides. Religion influenced, to a degree which today is difficult to appreciate, men's outlook on society. Economic and social changes acted powerfully on religion.

The universal habit of mind was biblical. People whose fathers and grandfathers had been tortured, burned at the stake, and buried alive for the offense of reading Scripture for themselves might be expected, when they did read it, to construe it literally and in a grim manner. They did. Bunyan's Pilgrim's Progress was the authentic account of what happened to the righteous spirit in its passage through this world to the next. The poor were friends of God. They knew for sure they would not meet the rich man in the Kingdom of Heaven. Avarice was a deadly sin. Pursuit of gain was the way to damnation. Money changers, speculators, and traders had always about them that certain odor that came from supping with Satan. To buy cheap and sell dear was extortion. Land was the only honorable form of wealth. Business was the ignoble part of the social anatomy.

The Age of Discovery

But the world had something to say for itself, and the world, too, had something to believe. Somehow, for the first time in the history of human thought, the idea of progress had appeared. It was the Age of Discovery. Knowledge was increasing; and this was not revealed knowledge of things hereafter, but knowledge of things here and now. After all, since everybody had to pass through this world whether he liked it or not, why shouldn't man improve his environment if he could by the practical application of knowledge? Although no one understood them clearly, although there was no such word as economics, great economic changes were taking place, and the realities were uncontrollable.

The religious mind stood in a bad dilemma. It could sense the oncoming world, almost as if it had a premoni­tion of the modern era, and yet it had no way of meeting it and was in fact forbidden by the Bible to meet it at all. Thus it became involved in extreme contradictions. For example, to lend money at interest was unchristian. For money to earn money was usury, and usury was sin. Yet as the necessities of trade increased, the economic function of the moneylender was one that somehow had to be performed, with the result that the Jews were brought in to do for Christians what Christians were morally unable to do for themselves. That is one of the reasons why the Jews became the great moneylenders of Europe.

The question was: Could Bunyan's hero, Christian, be­come an economic man and at the same time save his soul? The Dutch were the first to say positively yes, and this was significant, because the Dutch had paid more for religious liberty than any other people. They had carried their struggle for it to a plane of appalling heroism. Sooner than yield, they were willing to accept total doom. Their resistance so infuriated the Holy Office of the In­quisition that on February 16, 1568, all the inhabitants of the Netherlands were sentenced to death as heretics and Bible readers, except only a few persons especially named in the edict. In Motley's classic, The Rise of the Dutch Republic, one may read that-

Men in the highest positions were daily and hourly dragged to the stake. Alva, in a single line to Philip, coolly estimates the number of executions which were to take place immediately after the expiration of the Holy week at 800 heads.

Tolerance and Trade

If the spirit of laissez faire had been less than immortal, it could never have passed through that valley of death. What emerged was the Dutch Republic, founded on the ashes of its martyrs, dedicated to liberty of conscience, holding aloft a light for the world.

Then an amazing thing happened. The prosperity of Holland became the wonder and envy of Europe. In the trade of the world it advanced to first place, and took what Tawney calls the role of economic schoolmaster to seventeenth century Europe.

The power of individualism now for the first time was released to perform its examples. The result was that tolerance and trade flourished together.

The English came to it slowly and roundabout. Calvin­ism as they had got it from Geneva was a severe and rigid doctrine. It perceived very clearly that the three aspects of man were spiritual, political, and economic;  but since in two of these aspects he was wicked, or much tempted to be, the church was obliged not only to mind his soul but to impose severe discipline upon his political and economic activities. Its regulation of business was medieval and precise; it made ethical and social laws to govern such matters as the use of capital, usury, the just price, profits, the profit motive itself, wages, labor rela­tions, contracts, and trade agreements.

It remained for the Puritans of England to make the great rational construction of this doctrine. They could not understand why God should not admire success in work. Was not the universe his work? Why not suppose that the plan of its just order required his children to work and to succeed? If in money-making there were spiritual hazards, then all the more reason for keeping it straight with God. The way to do that was to put God in the shop. Where else could one be so sure of his presence and blessing? In the Puritan doctrine the word "calling" was one of special meaning. "God doth call every man and woman to serve in some peculiar employment, both for their own and the common good."

There was a spir­itual calling and a temporal calling. The Christian's duty was to take part in the practical affairs of the world, and to succeed in the world could be only a sign that God witnessed his work and was pleased with it. If riches were added to him, that, too, would be to the glory of God. In any case, he would never be idle rich, like Dives. Whether riches were good or bad was a question to be settled between the rich man and God; but idleness, thriftlessness, and profligacy were positive evils.

So it was that in the Puritan creed religious liberty and economic freedom were reconciled. The church would let business alone and trust God in the shop to keep it from evil.

Political Freedom and the Industrial Revolution

The next struggle was to get business free from the restrictions imposed upon it by government, not in the name of morals, but in the name of policy.

When that stormy cape had been rounded, the victory of laissez faire was complete, and the way was open for that great outburst of European energy which brought on the Industrial Revolution, led by England.

The medieval epoch was finished. Individualism was exalted to a way of life. The foundations of modern capi­talism were laid. The powers of government were limited. Free enterprise began. In pursuit of his economic ends, on his way to transform the world, European man was released from the restraints and sanctions imposed upon him both by the ecclesiastical tyranny and a vast bureau­cratic system of administrative law. Looking at it later when most of the consequences were already clear, Mon­tesquieu, the French philosophical historian, said "the English had progressed furthest of all people in three im­portant things -- piety, commerce, and freedom."

That would have been about 1750. For more than 200 years the spirit of laissez faire had been acting irresisti­bly, and yet that name for it was not known. The words had been used by the Physiocrats in 1736 in France, but hardly anywhere else; nor were they familiar to anybody in England when sixty years later, in 1810, a Commission in the House of Commons said:

No interference of the legislature with the freedom of trade and with the perfect liberty of each individual to dispose of his time or of his labor in the way or on the terms which he may judge most conducive to his own interest, can take place without violating general principles of the first importance to the prosperity and happiness of the community.

In those words government, the British government at least, renounced the right to touch business at all. No more forthright statement of the doctrine of laissez faire has perhaps ever been written. Mark, however, that the words do not appear in that statement. They were of French origin, written at first laissez nous faire, meaning "let us alone," and then laissez faire, meaning, "let it be." They expressed a philosophic idea. The idea was that the movements of society were spontaneous, not artificial, and that if you let them alone the results in the end, or, as the economist now says, in the long run, would be better for society as a whole-the idea, that is, of a natural order in which there is implicit harmony between public and private interest.

The point is that the spirit of laissez faire had already brought into the world religious liberty and freedom of enterprise, and that the foundations of what now may be called laissez faire capitalism had already been laid be­fore the words were familiar or had any epithetical meaning.

Wealth of Nations

Most people would probably say that the bible of laissez faire capitalism was written by Adam Smith. His Wealth of Nations appeared in 1776. Since some French economists had been using the term for forty years, Adam Smith must have heard it, and yet in the index to Wealth of Nations (Cannan Edition) you will find no reference to it. Then people say, "Yes, but it is implicit," and ask you to remember the famous passage about the invisible hand. In the index to the Wealth of Nations there is a reference to that passage and it reads as follows:

If each individual, therefore, endeavors as much as he can both to employ his capital in the support of domestic industry and so to direct that industry that its products may be of the greatest of value; each individual necessarily labors to render the annual revenue of society as great as he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest or knows how much he is promoting it . . . he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was not part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for society that it was not part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of society more effectually than when he really intends to pro­mote it. I have never known much good was done by those who affected to trade for the public good.

You may take that to express the doctrine of economic laissez faire, but the true meaning goes far beyond eco­nomics and belongs to the philosophy of individualism, founded upon the faith that man's spontaneous works will be more than his reason can explain. Adam Smith did not invent that philosophy, nor in his exposition of it did he surpass others who wrote before him, notably Adam Ferguson, who said:

Nations stumble upon establishments which are indeed the results of human action but not the result of human design.

Poetically, the same thought was expressed in Mande­ville's Fable of  the Bees. More than a century before Adam Smith's time, John Moore was saying in England:

It is an undeniable maxim that everyone by the light of na­ture and reason will do that which makes for his greatest ad­vantage. . . . The advancement of private persons will be the advantage of the public.

Twenty years after the Wealth of  Nations appeared, Edmund Burke, another great exponent of individualism, was referring to:

. . . the benign and wise disposer of all things who obliges men, whether they will or not, in pursuing their own selfish interests, to connect the general good with their own individual success.

He need not have got that from Adam Smith, for laissez faire by that time was already ascendant in the economic world, its principies were known and its works were observable.

Objections to Laissez Faire

Nearly 150 years ago Sismondi and his friends, evolving the theory of state socialism, were attacking laissez faire on four points, namely:

  1. That the fancied harmony between private and public interest did not in fact exist, wherefore liberty of the individual to pursue his own economic advantage would leave human needs in the lurch;

  2. That it would lead to serious inequalities in the distribu­tion of wealth.

  3. That it elevated materialism and success, and,

  4. That it involved society in such social catastrophes as mass unemployment.

And all of this was before steamships, railroads, elec­tricity, gasoline, motor cars, automatic machines, or mass production- even before there was such a thing in the world as a piece of farm machinery.

At that time all economic and political thought in Europe was basically pessimistic. Nobody could imagine that in the next few generations, under laissez faire capitalism, consumable wealth would be so prodigiously multiplied that the luxuries of the rich in one generation would become the necessary satisfactions of the poor in the next, and that from time to time surplus-a strange word for an incredible thing-would be the superficial cause of economic depression and unemployment. There had never been surplus before. There had never been too much of anything. Poverty was thought to be permanent and irreducible.

Inroads Against Poverty

The idea that poverty could be abolished did not arise in Europe. That was an American idea. And it could arise here, not because this country was rich in natural re­sources, but because here the conditions of laissez faire capitalism were more nearly realized than anywhere else in the world. Under stress of unlimited and uncontrolled competition we made the discovery that broke Europe's "iron law of wages" -- the law, namely, that since wages were paid out of the profits of capital, the wage fund was limited by the capital fund, and the capital fund was something that could be increased only in a slow and painful manner by limiting consumption.

We discovered that wages were not paid out of profits. They were paid out of production. Therefore, wages and profits could rise together, if only you increased produc­tion. Moreover, production itself created capital, as in the Ford example-the example of a company that began with $28,000 in cash and at the end of forty-five years employed in its work $1 billion of capital, all its own and all created out of production. And this was done by making the motor car so cheap that almost nobody was too poor to be able to possess and enjoy it.

American Capitalism

Those who speak of capitalism as if it were in itself a kind of universal order, with hierarchy, creed, and ortho­doxy, are either unable to make distinctions or find that distinctions inconvenience their  argument.  Capitalism takes its character from the soil and climate in which it grows. American capitalism is so unlike European capi­talism that the two could hardly be transplanted. Why has American capitalism been so much more productive than capitalism anywhere else? The seed was European. The sapling was not. Why did this one tree grow to a size and a fruitfulness so prodigious that all the people of the world come begging for its windfall?

There was here neither skill nor knowledge not pos­sessed also by the people in Europe. Yet after five gen­erations, with less than one-tenth of the earth's land area and less than one-fifteenth of its total population, we have now in our hands one-half of the industrial power of the whole world. Europe's star did not fall. That is not what happened. The American star dimmed it out. What made that difference between our creative power and that of Europe?

The difference was that here the magic of liberty was acting as it never had acted anywhere before.

Until the American Declaration of Independence, said Lord Acton, the history of freedom would have been "a history of the thing that was not."

American capitalism not only has been the most suc­cessful in the world; it is the one great citadel of eco­nomic freedom surviving and now carries the burden of defending Christian civilization against its Eastern en­emy. From this it follows that when you compare capi­talism with communism, the comparison is in fact be tween American capitalism, with its Puritan tradition, and Russian communism, which is uncompromisingly materialistic and atheistic.

The two ancient enemies of laissez faire were the state and the church. Laissez faire represented the principle of radicalism in both religion and economics. Radicalism was the sword of liberty. Neither the state nor the church has ever loved liberty. Now, what was conservative is radical, and laissez faire, which was radical, is reactionary. The wheel has gone all the way around.

______

Mr. Garrett (1878-1954), author of The Rise of Empire, The Ameri­can Story, and numerous other books, for many years edited Ameri­can Affairs for the National Industrial Conference Board. This ex­cerpt is reprinted by permission from the Winter 1949 number of American Affairs.