Government In The Housing Business

This article is condensed from Dr. Schmidt’s testimony of May 19, 1959 before the Sub­committee on Housing of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee.

My name is Emerson P. Schmidt, Director of Economic Re­search of the Chamber of Com­merce of the United States. I am here on request to discuss the questions submitted to me by the Subcommittee:

"What are the prospects for an adequate supply of residential con­struction labor during the period 1961-70? To what extent will the per unit labor costs increase or de­crease the per unit cost of housing during the period 1961-70? How should federal programs be sup­plemented or modified to improve prospects for an adequate supply?"

An unraised question occurred to me: Why has our national gov­ernment become so deeply and heavily involved in the people’s housing? This Subcommittee, the Senate Committee on Banking and Currency, the entire Congress as well as hundreds, perhaps thou­sands, of witnesses and industry people over the last 25 years have spent an enormous amount of time and energy and money considering and discussing housing, housing legislation, financing, and related problems. Had all this legislative activity not taken place, would our citizens be less well housed today, or would they be better housed? Would unit housing costs be higher or lower?

The answers to these basic ques­tions are not obvious. Yet, to a nonexpert, they would seem to be important.

For example, let us take a look at the accompanying table which may help us to consider one of these basic questions.

The table contrasts nonfarm housing starts in two prosperous years in the mid-1920′s and two prosperous years in the mid-1950′s. The figures show that 35 years ago, without government in­tervention, we had over 5 new non­farm housing starts per $1,000,000 of GNP (in constant 1954 prices), as against only about 3 housing starts in the mid-1950′s. Housing starts in the mid-1920′s per thou­sand population were moderately higher than in the mid-1950′s.

Offhand, this unfavorable show­ing for the government interven­tionist period causes one to wonder whether all this congressional con­cern for housing was justified in the past 20 or 25 years, and whether its continuation in the future is wise.

Whether other comparisons and more refined and more comprehen­sive analysis would put the gov­ernment interventionist period in a less unfavorable light would be worth further study. The figures in the table are not submitted to prove any conclusion; but they do suggest, at least superficially, that the Subcommittee members should ask themselves whether the proper next steps should be in the direc­tion of more and more government intervention, or, rather, a move in the opposite direction. If the figures are relevant and reasonably representative, they suggest that this Subcommittee and the Con­gress have been needlessly wor­ried and concerned with the American people’s housing prob­lems. The fact that housing is a basic human need does not neces­sarily mean that it is a public, rather than private, economic problem. There are other needs just as "basic."

The late, great Professor Joseph P. Schumpeter of Harvard Uni­versity often observed that America is in danger of being one of the first great modern nations to be socialized because something has happened to our spirit. Alexis de Tocqueville, in 1836, said:

HOUSING STARTS IN THE UNITED STATES

 

Without Aid

1925   1926

With Government Aid

1955     1956

Nonfarm   Housing      Starts              (thousands)

937

849

1,329

1,118

Gross   National         Product*           (billion dollars)

161.8

170.8

392.7

402.2

Population  (millions)

115.8

117.4

165.3

168.2

Housing   Starts per Million Dollars GNP*

5.79

4.97

3.38

2.78

Housing Starts per Thousand Population

8.09

7.23

8.04

6.65

 

*Gross National Product adjusted to reflect the same value o the dollar as in 1954.

"In America… the citizen… never thinks of soliciting the co­operation of the government; but he publishes his plan, offers to ex­ecute it himself, courts the as­sistance of other individuals, and struggles manfully against all ob­stacles. Undoubtedly he is often less successful than the State might have been in his position; but in the end, the sum of these private undertakings far exceeds all that the government could effect."

Many of our citizens, it seems, have lost the profound insights of our forebearers and men like de Tocqueville with respect to the great individual and social gains which can come through this in­dividual effort and self-reliance. We seem to have become victims of what has been called "the social­ization of the soul."

Perhaps here we have the key to the absence of superior per­formance in recent decades, even with all our government interven­tion, as against the performance in our earlier history, for example, in the 1920′s mentioned above. Again, I do not want to draw any dogmatic conclusions, but this Subcommittee might think seri­ously about the kind of society we have and the kind of society we want to build. Where does indi­vidual responsibility end? And where should government intervention start? What are the state and local responsibilities, as against the central government’s responsibility?

No Shortages in Free Market

The essentially private character of housing as a commodity and the historical record suggest that the questions which the Subcommittee put to me are easily resolved, even though incapable of concrete, quantitative answers.

Even in the first one, "What are the prospects for an adequate sup­ply of residential construction la­bor during the period 1961-70?" it would seem obvious that if neither labor unions nor government cre­ate any roadblocks, labor mobility and individual personal incentives will assure an "adequate" supply of construction labor to meet the bulging requirements of the 1960′s. The word "adequate" has little meaning, of course, except in terms of voluntary participa­tion by workers in construction trades and the demand for the services of workers in general in alternative employments.

We might put the matter an­other way, in the form of a dif­ferent question: Has any effective demand (desire, coupled with abil­ity and willingness to pay) for any commodity or service ever re­mained unfulfilled for any extended period because of the scarcity of common or skilled labor? Except for very short periods, such as a few days or weeks, it would be difficult to identify any significant consumer demand in peacetime which has ever been left unsati­ated because of a scarcity of labor.

Thus, it seems to me that this question enters needlessly into an arena where market forces can be relied upon to furnish the correct answer, provided, of course, no artificial restraints or stimulants are put in the way of these forces. It is the function of the free mar­ket, the free price (wage) system, and the self-interest motive to al­locate human and other resources in response to free consumer de­mand.

On the other hand, if artificial forces tend to overstimulate hous­ing starts, when the remainder of the economy is in a buoyant state, an apparent shortage of both labor and materials might occur.

After all, when permitted to do so, the price system does work. In 1934, average hourly earnings in manufacturing were $.53 and in building construction $.79, or 50 per cent higher. By 1959, aver­age hourly earnings in manufac­turing had reached $2.21, or 417 per cent of the 1934 figure, while average hourly earnings in build­ing construction had reached $3.18, or 403 per cent of the 1934 figure.

No labor leader, no businessman, no labor arbitrator, and no govern­ment bureau is wise enough to say what wage rates ought to be. But if permitted to do so, the market will provide the answer. Why have wages in manufacturing gone up slightly faster since 1934 than in building construction (particularly so, since fringe benefits in manu­facturing are also larger than in the building trades)? Supply and demand forces unquestionably were at work. Some might argue that even as long ago as 1934, con­struction labor was too expensive, relatively speaking; although I would have no information to sup­port such a view. But, probably, the rise in construction wages has been retarded, relatively to those in manufacturing, because of sub­stitution effects.

If construction labor is in fact overpriced or deliberate shortages are created by closed unions, un­duly high initiation fees, or un­necessarily long apprenticeship training periods, this will raise the price of construction labor in the organized trades. But, if these oc­cupations are relatively more re­munerative, additional people will be attracted to the industry in those areas of the economy where this is permitted—that is to say, where the union does not have complete control of job opportuni­ties.

Furthermore, such overpricing will put a high premium on pre­fabrication and the related trends. It seems altogether probable that the on-site labor requirements for residential construction will dimin­ish year by year in the decade ahead. The use of component con­struction, subassemblies, and mod­ular design will increase greatly. If it should happen that a scarcity of construction labor develops in the decade ahead, these powerful forces will be accelerated, quite probably, to the point where any serious labor scarcity will be fairly promptly overcome. But local bot­tlenecks for particular skills will continue from time to time, as they have in the past.

Ways To Break Bottlenecks

Even if the labor leaders were so unwise as to put restrictions on the use of labor-saving methods and components, then building materials firms, contractors, and consumers—that is, the house buyers—are not necessarily under permanent restraint; they have ways of getting around this.

By the supply of labor, we, of course, don’t merely mean so many bodies. The economic concept of labor supply involves not only the number of human beings, but also their ability, their skill, their work habits, and the number of hours they are willing to work per week. Reductions in the length ofthe work week or feather-bedding or restrictions on the use of labor­saving devices are ways of effec­tively reducing the supply of labor. Without government support, un­ions cannot hold back the tide of progress for long.

Thus, it is likely in some locali­ties and at some times that con­struction trades may overprice their services and restrict output. There are powerful price and tech­nological forces working in the other direction; so that it would appear to be improbable that we would have any secular deficiency of construction labor supply in the period ahead or that unit housing costs, for identical products, will rise relatively.

Labor costs, of course, are not merely a question of hourly wage rates, but also of fringe benefits and of labor input, of productivity. And productivity, of course, is a result of improved tools, manage­ment, technology, components, ma­terials, and the like, as well as labor. If wage rates should rise unduly, or restrictive practices—including unduly short work weeks—occur, this will put a very high premium on a massive reduction in on-site labor, and a great in­crease in the use of components which are factory-made, and will give additional impetus to prefab­rication and all the movements in that direction.